On or about 13 November I went looking for the quoted search term
"cost-push" at some 30 blogs I've been to many times over the years.
Made some notes and did nothing with them, just gathered em up.
On or about 20 December I noticed, new from Dietrich Vollrath, When did productivity growth slow down? Vollrath is usually a good read.
Some questionable stuff in his post, such as
The received wisdom is that we are living through a period of slow
TFP growth, and that this slowdown in TFP growth kicked in around the
early 2000s.
But I’m not sure that’s the whole story.
Not sure??
And there's some unquestionable stuff in there, like
When you zoom out further you’ll find that if there was a slowdown in
productivity growth it started in the late 1960s or early 1970s and has
continued through today.
and
If we’re having a discussion about what went “wrong”, then we need to look way earlier than the early 2000s to figure it out.
I
always want to look earlier, so definitely yes to that. And I've known
since forever that the productivity slowdown started mid-70s but more
recently I question that date, and Vollrath's "late 1960s" is the kind
of earlier that I like to look at.
//
On or about today, I was looking thru my "cost-push" notes of the 13th and found this excerpt from Inadequate Productivity + Rising Rates of Return on Capital = Reduced Labor Share of Income:
A
change occurred in the late 1960s / early 1970s, however, as labor
productivity slowed. Under the then-current regime, labor income
continued to grow in line with the economy, maintaining its share of
total income. Because productivity was no longer rising as much as
previously, though, the return on capital consistent with a constant
share of total income could not deliver an adequate rate of return –
a profit squeeze ensued. This drove firms to increase prices, leading
to larger wage demands and cost-push inflation.
from Postings from along the Trail... by hmg, Jr.
In
my notes there was only the excerpt, no evaluation. Maybe I gave it a
little extra attention today because of the "late 1960s" thing coming on
the heels of Vollrath's "late 1960s" thing. Whatever the reason, this
hit me hard today:
- labor
productivity slowed
- labor income
continued to grow
- a profit squeeze ensued
- and cost-push inflation.
Usually, when you look up cost-push inflation, you find something like
rising costs push up prices.
Usually
the rising costs are wages and oil. If you are as unimaginative as I
am, and you read article after article after article looking for
something more, you get nothing but tired of reading the same story over
and over again.
That's why my "financial cost-push" theory strikes me as such a big deal, and why hmg Jr's
productivity decline as the source of cost-push pressure
concept
is such a thrilling thought. With cost-push, you only need something to
get it started. After that, the solution to the problem of rising costs
creates more rising costs, and you've got a spiral. With hmg Jr's
explanation and my own, I now have two explanations of how cost-push got started.
//
hmg, Jr puts the start of the productivity slowdown at 1965, right where Allan Meltzer puts the start of the Great Inflation.
//
So
we start with high productivity in the post-WWII period, and a rule
that says wages should increase with productivity. It's a nice rule
because it means we can afford to buy the output we produce. Equilibrium
is satisfied, and economists are happy.
But then productivity
drops off, and before you know it wages have gone up more than the rule
allows. A high wage share means a low profit share, and that is a
problem. The problem is solved by suppressing wages and restoring profit
share.
Great.
I'm not sure how this all works, with
productivity and growth complicating things. Let me imagine an economy
where productivity -- output per hour -- grows 3% per year, and
everything else is ceteris paribus fixed.
So output grows at 3%,
labor gets two-thirds, capital gets one-third, and I don't know why it
works but I think that is the story. And everything is fine for a while.
And then productivity falls by half.
So now output grows at 1.5%.
If labor still gets two-thirds and capital still gets one-third,
everybody gets half what they got before. (So I could see right away
that cost pressure rises, because everyone wants as big a piece of the
pie as they got before. That part I got.)
For some reason it is
not okay if capital has to take a cut, but it is okay if labor has to
take a cut. I don't know whether the reason is economic or political,
but capital still has to get 1%. Before, when they got 1%, there was 2%
left over for labor. Now there is only half a percent left over for
labor.
And that's pretty much the story hmg, Jr. tells.
//
There
are still a lot of loose ends between my ears, but I think I have the
general picture. It's just the increase that gets reduced, not the whole
amount, assuming I understand the process.
In the time of 3%
productivity, if we got 100 last year then this year we get 103%. In the
time of 1.5% productivity, if we got 100 last year then this year we
get 101.5%. The 100 doesn't go down, just the addition gets smaller. And
labor's share of the addition gets smaller.
In the Economic Forecast
post, however, hmg, Jr. foresees further decline due to the retirement
of the baby boomers and the consequent fall in the size of the labor
force:
Whereas from the 1970s until the advent of the baby boom's
retirement, reduced productivity growth allowed for either rising real wages
and constant real profits (a falling return to investment), or rising
real profits (a constant return to investment) and constant real
wages, it is unlikely that this will continue. For real profits to
continue to increase, delivering a constant return to investment,
real wages must now fall. The “game” has changed from one approximated by zero
sums, to a closer approximation by negative sums.
If
productivity goes below 1%, then for capital to get its 1%, labor has
to give up its productivity gain entirely, and more besides. (Except now it's not productivity falling. It's labor force size.)
//
I
don't see hmg, Jr. addressing the question of why productivity fell.
Maybe I missed it. I've heard it said, though, that productivity fell
because baby boomers brought to the labor force their inexperience in
quantity sufficient to cause that decline in productivity.
Nice,
right? I'm a baby boomer. When I started working, I made productivity
fall. And then by retiring, I made things worse again. I just can't win.
//
Meanwhile, hmg Jr. lays out a clear picture:
Measuring a real standard of living by real output per capita as “Y/N”, labor
productivity as “Y/L”, and labor per capita as “L/N” –
where “Y” is real aggregate output, “L” is aggregate hours
worked, and “N” is the level of population – the following
equation relates them: Y/N = Y/L * L/N.
The equation Y/N = Y/L * L/N is a version of growth accounting. Dan Sichel:
The speed at which the economy can grow over a longer horizon is
determined by changes in two main factors: the total amount people are
working — which involves both the number of workers in the labor force
and the hours they work — and the efficiency with which they produce
goods and services.
Let me repeat what I said the other day:
I have no trouble
accepting the idea that an increase in the labor force or an increase in
productivity can boost economic output. But I cannot accept the
ridiculous notion that nothing else plays a role in boosting output.
I think we have to go back to why productivity fell. I think it has to do with cost.